Welcome to DU!
The truly grassroots left-of-center political community where regular people, not algorithms, drive the discussions and set the standards.
Join the community:
Create a free account
Support DU (and get rid of ads!):
Become a Star Member
Latest Breaking News
Editorials & Other Articles
General Discussion
The DU Lounge
All Forums
Issue Forums
Culture Forums
Alliance Forums
Region Forums
Support Forums
Help & Search
World History
Related: About this forumEmperor Wang Mang: China's First Socialist?
Wang Mang may be the most controversial of Chinas hundred or more emperors. Born into one of his countrys oldest noble families in about 45 B.C., he was celebrated first as a scholar, then as an ascetic and finally as regent for a succession of young and short-lived emperors. Finally, in 9 A.D., with the death (many believe the murder) of the last of these infant rulers, Wang seized the throne for himself. His usurpation marked the end of the Former Han Dynasty, which had reigned since 206 B.C.shortly after the death of Chinas renowned First Emperor, builder of the Great Wall and the celebrated Terracotta Army. In the Hans place, Wang proclaimed the Xinnewdynasty, of which he was destined to remain the solitary emperor.
-snip-
More recently, however, Wang Mang has undergone a startling reappraisal. This process can be dated to 1928 and the publication of a study by Hu Shih, a renowned scholar who was then the Chinese ambassador to the United States. In Hus view, it was the Han Dynasty that most richly deserved condemnation, for having produced a long line of degenerate scions. Wang Mang, on the other hand, lived simply, thought deeply and was the first man to win the empire without an armed revolution. Moreover, Wang then nationalized his empires land, distributed it equally to his subjects, cut land taxes from 50 percent to 10, and was, all in all, frankly communistica remark Hu intended as a compliment.
-snip
The little that is known about Wang Mangs reforms can be summarized as follows. It is said he invented an early form of social security payments, collecting taxes from the wealthy to make loans to the traditionally uncreditworthy poor. He certainly introduced the six controlsgovernment monopolies on key products such as iron and salt that Hu Shih saw as a form of state socialismand was responsible for a policy known as the Five Equalizations, an elaborate attempt to damp down fluctuations in prices. Even Wangs harshest modern critics agree that his ban on the sale of cultivated land was an attempt to save desperate farmers from the temptation to sell up during times of famine; instead, his state provided disaster relief. Later the emperor imposed a ruinous tax upon slave owners. It is equally possible to interpret this tax as either an attempt to make slaveholding impossible or as a naked grab for money.
-snip-
Historians are divided as to Wang Mangs intentions. Several, led by Bielenstein, suggest that catastrophic changes in the course of the Yellow River took place during his regency period, resulting in famine, drought and flood; if this is true, it can certainly be argued that Wang spent his entire reign battling forces that he could not possibly control. But the majority of modern accounts of Wangs reign see him as a Confucian, not a communist. Bielenstein, in his contribution to the imposing Cambridge History of China, says this, though he chooses to ignore some of the more contentious issues. And while Clyde Sargent (who translated the History of the Han Dynasty) acknowledges the startling modernity of the emperors ideas, he adds that there is insufficient evidence to prove he was a revolutionary. For Oxford Universitys Homer Dubs, author of the standard account of Wangs economic policies, the emperors new coins were issued in conscious imitation of an ancient tradition, dating to the Warring States period, of circulating two denominations of bronze coins. Indeed, the emperors monetary policy, Dubs writes, can be viewed as a purely Confucian practice, since a cardinal Confucian principle was the imitation of the ancient sages; he also points out that the loans the emperor made available to needy persons came with a high interest rate, 3 percent per month. Moreover, few of the emperors most apparently socialist policies remained in force in the face of widespread protest and rebellion. In the abolition of slavery and the restriction of land holdings, Dubs writes, Wang Mang undoubtedly hit upon a measure that would have benefited society, but these reforms were rescinded within two years.
-snip-
More recently, however, Wang Mang has undergone a startling reappraisal. This process can be dated to 1928 and the publication of a study by Hu Shih, a renowned scholar who was then the Chinese ambassador to the United States. In Hus view, it was the Han Dynasty that most richly deserved condemnation, for having produced a long line of degenerate scions. Wang Mang, on the other hand, lived simply, thought deeply and was the first man to win the empire without an armed revolution. Moreover, Wang then nationalized his empires land, distributed it equally to his subjects, cut land taxes from 50 percent to 10, and was, all in all, frankly communistica remark Hu intended as a compliment.
-snip
The little that is known about Wang Mangs reforms can be summarized as follows. It is said he invented an early form of social security payments, collecting taxes from the wealthy to make loans to the traditionally uncreditworthy poor. He certainly introduced the six controlsgovernment monopolies on key products such as iron and salt that Hu Shih saw as a form of state socialismand was responsible for a policy known as the Five Equalizations, an elaborate attempt to damp down fluctuations in prices. Even Wangs harshest modern critics agree that his ban on the sale of cultivated land was an attempt to save desperate farmers from the temptation to sell up during times of famine; instead, his state provided disaster relief. Later the emperor imposed a ruinous tax upon slave owners. It is equally possible to interpret this tax as either an attempt to make slaveholding impossible or as a naked grab for money.
-snip-
Historians are divided as to Wang Mangs intentions. Several, led by Bielenstein, suggest that catastrophic changes in the course of the Yellow River took place during his regency period, resulting in famine, drought and flood; if this is true, it can certainly be argued that Wang spent his entire reign battling forces that he could not possibly control. But the majority of modern accounts of Wangs reign see him as a Confucian, not a communist. Bielenstein, in his contribution to the imposing Cambridge History of China, says this, though he chooses to ignore some of the more contentious issues. And while Clyde Sargent (who translated the History of the Han Dynasty) acknowledges the startling modernity of the emperors ideas, he adds that there is insufficient evidence to prove he was a revolutionary. For Oxford Universitys Homer Dubs, author of the standard account of Wangs economic policies, the emperors new coins were issued in conscious imitation of an ancient tradition, dating to the Warring States period, of circulating two denominations of bronze coins. Indeed, the emperors monetary policy, Dubs writes, can be viewed as a purely Confucian practice, since a cardinal Confucian principle was the imitation of the ancient sages; he also points out that the loans the emperor made available to needy persons came with a high interest rate, 3 percent per month. Moreover, few of the emperors most apparently socialist policies remained in force in the face of widespread protest and rebellion. In the abolition of slavery and the restriction of land holdings, Dubs writes, Wang Mang undoubtedly hit upon a measure that would have benefited society, but these reforms were rescinded within two years.
Interesting stuff. Apparently the group he was most trying to help, the peasantry, were the first to turn against him.
http://blogs.smithsonianmag.com/history/2011/12/emperor-wang-mang-chinas-first-socialist/